We're going to see many more pictures of starving polar bears

The latest news from the Great White North:

Polar bears in Canada’s Hudson Bay risk starvation as the climate crisis lengthens periods without Arctic Sea ice, despite the creatures’ willingness to expand their diets.

Polar bears use the ice that stretches across the ocean surface in the Arctic during colder months to help them access their main source of prey – fatty ringed and bearded seals.

In the warmer months when the sea ice recedes, they would be expected to conserve their energy and even enter a hibernation-like state.

But human-caused climate change is extending this ice-free period in parts of the Arctic – which is heating between two and four times faster than the rest of the world – and forcing the polar bears to spend more and more time on land.

New research looking at 20 polar bears in Hudson Bay suggests that without sea ice they still try to find food.

OK, this could be true. We’re certainly not saying that it isn’t. However, we just want to put a little warning down.

Pictures of starving polar bears won’t be proof that it is happening.

Which might seem a little odd but bear (sorry) with us.

End of life for an apex predator is not a happy time. After a life eating everything else there’s nothing that does come eat you once you’ve lost a pace. End of life for an apex predator is, likely enough, therefore starvation when the ability to hunt goes.

We also know that polar bear populations have expanded massively in recent decades.

We would therefore expect to be seeing more starving polar bears - that end of life fate of so many apex predators.

There’s also that larger point. The population of apex predators is kept in check by the plenitude of the prey species. Once that predator species reaches full exploitation of the food source then it is indeed starvation which keeps it in check.

Seeing, pictures of, or finding starving polar bears will not, therefore, be proof of this contention that climate change ice loss is causing polar bears to starve. Sure, such evidence might well be consistent with that contention, isn’t proof against it, but it’s not proof of it.

As with more whales washing up on beaches being consistent with ships, or seabed development noise from windfarms, or whatever, killing whales. It’s also consistent with, something we should expect to see in fact, from the truly massive expansion - and a righteous expansion too - in whale populations in recent decades.

Evidence is indeed evidence but the big question is always, well, evidence of what?

We would suggest, ever so gently, that some who might try to mislead us will use pictures of starving polar bears to insist upon the verity of that contention - that climate change induced ice loss is starving them. As we say, this could be true. But we need rather more proof than pictures of starving polar bears to prove it.

We'll admit to being terrible cynics about the fashion business

At least one of us was once accused of dressing like a 1970s DJ - which, upon consideration, we felt to be a step up from the usual description. So, it could well be said that fashion isn’t really and quite our thing.

Coach’s Stuart Vevers on sustainability in fashion: ’The change has to come from designers’

British designer credits a decade in New York with firing a ‘genuine passion’ for sustainability

This newfound insistence upon sustainability in fashion amuses us. For, of course, the entire point and purpose of fashion is to show who is in this season with the latest things and who is some regrettable oik still wearing something at least three weeks out of date. At the highest possible, most favourable, description the entire industry produces Veblen Goods.

Which is, of course, a problem when actual clothing - and designs - are now cheap as chips and getting cheaper by the week. Temu, Shein, Boohoo and the rest means that said oiks can be dressed in whatever at the same time as the cognoscenti. Which would never do, of course. Violating the main point of the game.

What is the point of catwalk shows, now that social media serves up fresh trends to everyone’s phone every day of the year? “[It] has to be about sustainability”, says Stuart Vevers, the British designer who has spent the last decade bringing fashion credibility and a new point of view to the once-staid American handbag brand Coach.

Fashion weeks hand the microphone of the cultural conversation to designers, and Vevers wants to use his airtime “to look at where sustainability can be scaled. Where we can scale is where we can have an impact.”

Thus the rules of the game must be changed. For if the base idea is the production of Veblen Goods then Veblen Goods there must be. So, now sustainability is in - a method of creating expensive things which people will buy because they are expensive and therefore “Look at Me!” as opposed to nice cotton t-shirts which just anyone can now have in abundance.

As someone once said about methods of eating asparagus (perhaps a Mitford?). Which one is used doesn’t matter, even firing it from miniature cannons into fellow diners’ mouths. But that there is a fashionable method which you don’t know about is vital. For that’s how the distinction between you and non-U is made.

Given the paucity of wildly wealthy economists out there it’s not true that a command of economic theory is a surefire way to make cash. But it is nice to see that The Theory of the Leisure Class is still relevant as a description of human behaviour 125 years later.

If we could make just a small suggestion to Mr Gove?

At the weekend Mr Gove warned that young people shut out of the UK’s housing market could spurn democracy and turn to authoritarianism.

“If people think that markets are rigged and a democracy isn’t listening to them, then you get – and this is the worrying thing to me – an increasing number of young people saying, ‘I don’t believe in democracy, I don’t believe in markets,” he said.

There is indeed something perverse about people looking at British housing and thinking that too much market is the problem. But if this belief is strongly held by the Minister - that the young will turn to authoritarianism if something isn’t done - then our little suggestionette.

Have more market in British housing.

Since 1947, under the Town and Country Planning Act and successors, the British land market has been centrally planned. As happens with all planning systems as the decades pass the system becomes ever more constipated and in need of a thorough colonic irrigation. The situation is such that the system simply needs to be destroyed.

Create a market again in British housing - blow up the TCPA. Proper blow up, kablooie.

It’s the only language the bureaucrats understand, d’ye see?

Oh dear, Matthew Syed appears to have swallowed some nonsense

We’ll accept that it could be just horrendously bad information and assumptions that have led to the tin foil hattery:

And here we glimpse the geopolitical significance of Ukraine. In the coming decades two things will prove crucial. First, we’ll need fossil fuels to keep the lights on in the short term; second, in the medium term we’ll need access to a wide variety of materials to build a renewable energy infrastructure (we can argue about the speed of the energy transition, but the transition itself is non-negotiable). This means that fossil fuel prices will continue to rise, providing a final windfall to suppliers (look at the money flowing to Saudi Arabia). But it also means that the price of some materials is set to spiral. These include lithium, cobalt, nickel, copper, manganese and “rare earths” like neodymium, used in electric vehicles and the magnets of wind turbines.

Ukraine isn’t an important source - not even an interesting source - of any of these materials. We’d also point out that the cobalt and lithium prices are currently below production costs - not a sign of a shortage - and rare earths are rapidly approaching that price.

Let’s circle back to Ukraine. Did you know that it has been described by Jonathan Maxwell in his superb book The Edge as a “mineral superpower”? Did you know it has the second-largest gas reserves in Europe after Norway? Or that the Donbas boasts one of the largest coal deposits in the world? And that Ukraine has stocks of 117 of the 120 most widely used metals and minerals, including manganese, sulphur, graphite, titanium and nickel? Did you know that one think tank has estimated the mineral wealth now under Russian control in Ukraine at $12.4 trillion, which is nearly four times the UK’s GDP (albeit the former is a stock, the latter a flow).

Now do you see the geopolitical importance of Ukraine?

That’s just argle bargle. Yes, we know the source. It’s nonsense.

The $12 trillion is the value of those minerals extracted, prepared and sitting on the dockside ready to ship. The actual value of those minerals is $12 trillion minus the costs of extraction and preparation. Which is, for a very rough and ready guide, likely to be about $12 trillion. The net present value of those minerals, in the ground, where they are, is around and about zero. We’d not be categoric about it being entirely nothing, but it’s not, if we’re using $12 trillion as our other measure, much above that nothing.

Ukraine isn’t even a major home for reserves (nor even resources) for the minerals identified, iron ore, titanium, strontium and so on. Yes, there’s some there, as there is some of everything else. Because there’s some of all those things near everywhere. Because the world is only made up, all of it, of those 90 things.

As to the claim about sulphur, really, Maaaate? Get a grip, it’s a waste product from processing high sulphur (of which there are lots and lots) fossil fuels. The usual problem is getting rid of it, not producing it - which is why it often goes for $50 a tonne, the cost of transport.

Seriously, the idea that columns are written on these assumptions, let alone their being actual geopolitical incentives, is an absurdity.

Give us a call Matthew, we’ll explain it to you. Then you can return your tin foil to wrapping your sandwiches, the use it’s intended for.

Just nonsense.

These sound like remarkably bad ideas

It’s entirely true that globalisation is changing and yet:

How about citizen consultations on bringing back some manufacturing? We may have clever ideas that politicos and their advisers have overlooked. America is embarking on a win-win strategy by subsidising companies that create green jobs: green transformation, new skilled jobs and less dependence on China. Imagine what a high-end chip plant in the West Midlands could do for Britain.

Jobs, as we never tire of pointing out, are a cost, not a benefit. Creating more jobs in the energy production system is creating more costs in the energy production system. Requiring more human labour to produce the same value of output also lowers labour productivity - by definition. And since average wages depend upon the average productivity of labour - not just depend upon, are determined by - this lowers all wages in the United States. This is not good policy.

As to citizens consultations of course these happen every time anyone buys anything. And a high end chip plant in the West Midlands? We have no one in the country who can actually run a high end chip plant - as the Americans are finding out there, tens of billions of $ have been sprayed at building the factories only to find out they’ve not got the workers.

It is entirely true that globalisation is changing but it’s changing in the right manner. Which is that market participants are experimenting with what to do and then doing more of what works, less of what doesn’t. Rather than change in globalisation being a green light for every planning stupidity that fools can come up with.

A change in how the market system allocates is not an excuse for not using the market system of allocation - quite the opposite.

Parkinson's and the EU Digital Services Act

We tend to think this is going to end up being a very bad idea indeed:

The EU Digital Services Act (DSA), which goes fully into force on in-scope digital services later this month but is already being applied on a sub-set of larger platform providers like Meta, makes provision for charging these so-called very large online platforms (VLOPs) and very large online search engines (VLOSE) to help fund the cost of the bloc’s oversight of their businesses.

The regulation stipulates that the amount charged annually should take into account the costs incurred by the European Commission, which is the primary enforcer of the DSA on VLOPs and VLOSE; and be “proportionate” to the size of the service (based on average active monthly regional users) and also factor in the provider’s “economic capacity”, or that of the designated service (or services) they offer. (In Meta’s case, it provides two services which are designated under the DSA: Its social networks, Facebook and Instagram.)

Now, yes, some of us here aren’t all that keen on the EU itself. Some have even campaigned against it - but there is no ASI “view” on the organisation. So this isn’t about the EU specifically.

It’s also not about regulation - although we have a well known antipathy to many forms of it around here.

This is, rather, about something very specific, the setting of that budget.

We know, from C. Northcote Parkinson, that the motivating force of a bureaucracy is simply the survival of that bureaucracy. Once that is achieved it is the growth in the budget of that bureaucracy and the associated headcount. Given that there can be no useful measure of the output of a bureaucracy that’s just what the motivating forces are.

This is simply a revealed truth and is why we do now have more Admirals than ships, why the MoD now has more than one bureaucrat per sailor or soldier and also what gave rise to Ronnie Reagan’s joke (the punchline of which is the D of Ag bureaucrat crying at his desk because “My farmer died”).

OK, we know this. So now we have a bureaucracy to “monitor” certain companies. But the budget is not determined by what taxpayers are willing to pay for such monitoring (not that that’s much of a limitation at EU level) nor, in fact, by anything very much. The more the bureaucracy spends - that is, the greater the desire for a higher headcount, and expanded budget - the more the captive companies under the law will have to pay.

We do not expect this to work out well. In fact, we’ll make a prediction.

Per the Commission, the total pot of supervisory fees it has collected from VLOPs/VLOSE for 2023 is €45.24M (~$48.7M).

That’s not going to remain about €45 million. That’s going to go north at 15 to 25% a year soon enough.

Come back and prove us wrong in 20 years.

We do know that Parkinson is right. And the nutshell argument about bureaucracy is that to put bureaucrats in charge of their own budget is to put children in charge of the sweetie shop. An amusing idea leading to hyperactivity but no long term good will come of it.

This isn’t a good idea.

We fear this claim might not be entirely true

Bill McKibben tells us that:

We now live on a planet where the cheapest way to produce power is to point a sheet of glass at the sun

If it is true then that’s excellent, we’ve solved climate change. All we have to do now is wait. As extant plants come to the end of their working life they will - entirely naturally, with no other incentive nor action needed - be replaced by sheets of glass pointed at the sun.

As no one at all does in fact believe this to be true - not even Bill McKibben - then we do have to assume that the statement is either not true or not believed by anyone. Possibly not believed by anyone on the basis that it’s not true.

The background here is the pause in granting new LNG export licences in the US. Something we dealt with back a bit. It’s actually an internal to the US argument over who gets the profits from fracking, nothing else.

It is possible to go a step further in analysing this claim. So, all those/us Europeans eager to buy this American LNG that isn’t to be exported. Why are we eager to buy it? It has to be because it’s cheaper than putting up sheets of glass pointed at the sun, doesn’t it? And if that’s the only possible explanation for the demand for the LNG then that statement about sheets of glass cannot be true, can it?

As we’ve been pointing out for a couple of decades now there are interesting things to say and discuss about climate change. But assertions of untruths don’t help.

Apparently we all have to be conned into being evil

Andrew Simms with his usual perspicacity here:

But the SUV craze has been driven by marketing, so an obvious step would be to introduce tobacco-style bans on their advertising.

Consumers are fools who only buy because they’re brainwashed by advertising. Ban the brainwashing and all will be well. Using the car industry - home of the Ford Edsel - as the proof of this contention is something we might describe as less than evidentially valid.

But how did we get here and what can be done? SUVs didn’t just swarm on to city streets like a natural phenomenon – even if that’s the impression the adverts like to create. In a very short period of time, consumer behaviour was switched on to the SUV by massive marketing campaigns and new consumer debt models, in the shape of personal contract purchase (PCP) loans. In 2010, SUVs accounted for just one in 10 new car sales in the EU, but by last year this had climbed to over half. It’s a stunning example of how quickly a heavily polluting sector can change. Unfortunately for human health and the climate, it has been in the wrong direction. Why is not hard to understand. In a saturated car market, manufacturers found they could charge more and make more profit from SUVs.

The contention is that consumers all went and bought SUVs because they are more expensive. Which is not only less than evidentially valid it’s insane.

Consumers will indeed buy something they consider to be worth more but that’s a different contention:

Then there is the other problem: electric or not, SUVs are killers. People in a light vehicle are three times more likely to get seriously injured when in collision with a much bigger car than one of similar weight.

Ah, SUVs are safer for those who buy SUVs. Which does seems like a good enough reason for people to preferentially buy SUVs. But this then has its problems when we consider Simms’ insistence on that advertising. It should be illegal to tell you about greater safety?

But of course the real joy here is what this means for EVs. Which are, naturally, considerably heavier than ICE cars. Therefore they have all the same problems as larger ICE cars. So, presumably, under the Simms dispensation advertising them should be illegal.

We did note the perspicacity which Mr. Simms brings to discussions, didn’t we?

Isn't this just so delightfully stupid?

What happens if the consumer decides not to buy an EV?

It is this confusion that is partly being blamed for the slow-motion car crash now unfolding in EV sales, with industry figures published on Monday showing that their market share slipped from 19.7pc in December to just 14.7pc in January.

That was after annual figures showed the proportion of car sales that were electric slipped from 16.6pc in 2022 to 16.5pc in 2023, the first time the EV segment has gone into reverse.

The next stage is massive fines - as much as £15,000 per vehicle in fact:

This requires 22pc of new cars sold this year to be ZEVs, rising to 28pc in 2025, 52pc in 2028 and 80pc by 2030. Manufacturers who fail to meet the targets must pay fines or cover shortfalls through an emissions trading scheme.

The poor old manufacturers are left pushing on a string.

The background logic here is what is stupid. We don’t have to go far to find someone who’ll tell us that what we buy is all determined by the Big Corporations. It’s advertisin’, innit? They brainwash us, right?

That near all advertising is not “Buy this!” but is “Buy my this!” seems to escape. But here we’ve actually got a test. Do consumers rule or producers?

We’ve also gone through this before. Producers were forced to lower the average CO2 emissions of their fleets. Rolls Royce, embedded within BMW, could do this. Bentley, within VW, as well. Aston Martin, selling only those sporting beasts, could not. Which is what gave us the Cygnet, about as silly a motoring idea as ever saw light of day and about as successful as the Ford Edsel.

Which is where our stupidity diagnosis comes in. Those Rolls Royce minds in Whitehall have designed a grand plan To Save The Planet. And they’ve done it on the most basic misdiagnosis of who is the decision maker in an economy. It isn’t the producers who shepherd the consumer sheep into buying whatever it is that is produced. It’s the consumer making the decision. And if the consumer says no then that’s that.

This entire plan for EVs is based upon producer sovereignty. But that’s not how the world works - consumer sovereignty is. And basing your grand plan To Save All Of Humanity on an incorrect piece of sub-Marxist wibble, well, that’s really pretty stupid, isn’t it.

We can see a certain problem with ethnic pay gap protection

Over and above the problem of this being attempted management of the economy at too great a level of detail that is. We simply do not believe that government is able to deal with things at this level of fineness. But as we say, beyond that.

Inequality has risen over the last decade, with BAME families disproportionately hit by the pandemic and the cost of living crisis, as well as being on the sharp end of cuts to the NHS, education and the criminal justice system.

Anneliese Dodds, the shadow women and equalities secretary, said: “It has never been more important to deliver race equality. Inequality has soared under the Tories and too many black, Asian and ethnic minority families are working harder and harder for less and less. This is holding back their families and holding back the economy.

The problem being in the numbers used to analyse or explain differences in ethnic pay, that ethnic pay gap.

On the raw figures British born Black, Asian or Asian British, Mixed or Multiple ethnic groups and Other ethnic groups all in fact get paid more than White. When we include overseas born Black with British born then that group does earn less. This is something that has happened in this past 5 or 6 years, from 2018 onwards or so, a reversal of the earlier paid less than.

When we drill down further into these numbers and correct for geography then the picture changes. For this higher pay is partly at least an artefact of the concentration of ethnic minorities in London, where pay is significantly higher than the rest of the country - but so are living costs as well.

When we drill down further to examine by education level and so on then the picture changes once again.

The point being that the situation is complex. And, OK, so it’s complex.

However, it’s complex in the opposite direction from the gender pay gap. On those raw, national, figures women earn less than men. On those raw, national, figures ethnic minorities earn more than whites. On the fully adjusted for working hours, jobs done, education levels, geography of workplace, job for job, parental status and so on then women do not earn less than men. But some ethnic minorities do earn less than whites, others more.

Which is, we think, something of a problem for at least one or the other set of complaints. If it is the properly adjusted gap that we should all worry about then gender pay has been solved. For which Hallelujah, obviously. If it is the raw and unadjusted gap that is the problem then there is nothing to do - unless we’re to start worrying that whites are underpaid - about the ethnic pay gap.

To change the method of measurement midstream as it were, to say that unadjusted is important when talking of gender and adjusted when talking of ethnicity is to, we would suggest, be overly picking and choosing which numbers to pay attention to. Almost as if there’s a manipulation of the figures in order to create a political issue that requires action.