Tim Worstall Tim Worstall

If people lose their jobs to AI they'll do.....something else

A certain error of logic here. We’re being told that we’ll not get richer from AI because AI will destroy jobs. But that’s the wrong way around. We’ll get richer from AI according to how many jobs AI destroys - the more destroyed the richer we shall collectively be.

The aim and purpose of all technological advance is to destroy jobs, after all.

From IPPR:

Almost 8 million UK jobs could be lost to artificial intelligence in a “jobs apocalypse”, according to a report warning that women, younger workers and those on lower wages are at most risk from automation.

How excellent is the correct reaction.

In the worst-case scenario for the second wave of AI, 7.9m jobs could be displaced, the report said, with any gains for the economy from productivity improvements cancelled out with zero growth in GDP within three to five years.

They’re just not getting it in the slightest. Sure, we agree, transitions can be difficult. But the end state of AI destroying 7.9 million jobs will be that we’re all richer by 7.9 million jobs.

A very basic observation about humans is that desires are unlimited. So, if we have more human labour available to tackle more human desires then that’s good - more human desires can be sated by that more human labour.

This is how we got the NHS, universities, ballet and professional sports after all. Back three centuries 90% of us had to spend all of life standing around in muddy fields growing the crops that kept 100% of the population alive. Then someone invented the tractor (as a shorthand for the mechanisation of farming) and we ended up needing only 2% of the population on the land. 88% were then free to go work in the NHS, universities, ballet and professional sports. We are now richer - because of the tractor - by whatever value we put upon the NHS, universities, ballet and professional sports.

We can say the same thing about the Spinning Jenny - the great wealth was that abolition of hundreds and hundreds of hours a year per person of entirely female labour in handspinning - and the washing machine (again, a shorthand for the mechanisation of much domestic labour). Formerly exclusively female and household labour disappeared into the maw of the machines leading to the economic emancipation of women - a very grand increase in human wealth.

AI destroys jobs that are currently done by human labour. That frees up human labour to do other things, sate other human desires for things that can be solved by human labour. Who knows, we might eventually be able to get the NHS to work properly, universities to educate and British sports teams that win something now and again. Ballet, well….

Of course, it’s possible to postulate that human desires are not unlimited. In which case there are no more things to be done with excess human labour - therefore leisure will rise. Given the number of people telling us that working hours should fall - all that 4 day week stuff - this is also an increase in human wealth. On the useful grounds that an increase in leisure with a maintained consumption level is an increase in human wealth.

There is no possible outcome of all that work disappearing into the machines that makes humans worse off. No, really. As Bill Nordhaus has shown. Imagine that all the money from the AI goes to capital, that the tech bros gain all the gains. We end up with:

If capital productivity is rapidly rising (which is the same statement as the robots are eating all our jobs) then yes, it's true, the plutocrats who own the machines end up getting (or, more accurately, asymptotically approach getting) 100% of the output of the economy. But at the same time, and because of this process, wages go up in real terms at 200% a year.

Transitions, ah, yes, transitions. But the end state simply cannot be a bad one. So, let’s do it, right?

Read More
Tim Ambler Tim Ambler

Generic Design Assessments

The UK nuclear strategy today is a muddle. After a brief description, this blog suggests what it should be.

The Government claims that it ensures “that any new nuclear power station built in Great Britain meets high standards for:

  • safety

  • security

  • environmental protection

  • waste management”

The process is called the Generic Design Assessment (GDA) which is claimed to take four years, though insiders say the average is nearer six. But that is less than half the time taken to approve the National Grid Electricity System Operator (ESO) plans to connect up to 86 gigawatts (GW) of offshore wind by 2035. If one is building just one nuclear power plant every 20 years, these bureaucratic delays may not matter much, but the new small modular reactor (SMR) technology means, if we are to achieve net zero by 2050, building five a year over the next 20 years. No chance of that unless the bureaucrats mend their ways.

The three stages of the GDA are: “Step 1 (initiation) which can take around 12 months. At its conclusion, ONR will publish a GDA Step 1 Statement setting out its regulatory position at this point. Step 2 (fundamental assessment) can take around 12 months, after which a GDA Step 2 Statement sets out ONR’s regulatory position at this point. Step 3 (detailed assessment) can take around 24 months. ONR will then publish one or both GDA Step 3 Statement and Decision Document.”

If a developer requires a GDA for the building of an SMR at one site only in the UK then the process can be halted after the successful conclusion of Step 2 followed by a Site Licence application. If the deployment of a particular SMR design is envisaged for multiple sites in the UK then Step 3 needs to be successfully concluded.

Although the four issues are supposed to be considered as an integrated whole, they can really be considered as two: safety determined by the Office for Nuclear Regulation and site approval determined by the Environment Agency.  Good progress was made on the former issue by the nuclear regulators in the US, Canada and UK agreeing that safety clearance in any one of the three would be regarded as approval by all three.  

The two-way (and hopefully now three-way) transatlantic agreement to harmonise the licensing process has thus far only tackled the administrative landscape work that occupies much of the first 2 years. There are few safety aspects to Stage 1 which could be reduced to 4 months in all 3 countries if a standardised and transportable approach is agreed. Note that activities covered by the various steps and/or stages of the UK, US and Canadian systems do not match precisely at this stage, and some harmonisation is still required. 

Stage 3 is where the actual design is critically scrutinised and an iterative dialogue with design teams is established. This work can take around 12-18 months depending upon the lineage and degree of novelty in the reactor design. If the applicant has a well-resourced design team that can respond quickly to regulator questions and design modifications, it can proceed quickly. In the case of the AP1000, there were still almost 1,000 issues raised by the ONR that remained (and still remain) unresolved. This is where delays can become significant and where developers may be to blame. Trying to design and license a new reactor on a shoestring budget can result in developers complaining to their shareholders that the regulator is being unreasonable. Institutional shareholders then lobby politicians to influence regulators to be more accommodating of the newcomers.

Terrapower has realised the importance of having an FOAK (First Of A Kind) site under development and adequate financial resources to quickly design, build and commission their first reactor. They are now putting pressure on the US NRC to bring the same urgency to their licensing application. 

There is one other point worth noting. The history of nuclear safety thus far, together with the accidents that have happened, have largely surrounded the use of water/steam as a coolant and transporter of heat energy from the reactor to where it is converted into mechanical and electrical energy. But when it comes to HTGRs and MSRs there is no high temperature and pressurised water in or around the reactor. These advanced SMRs have  much simpler and safer systems and this needs to be reflected in their design processing time.

How should it work? We need to distinguish, as the current system does not, between the traditional gigawatt reactors such as proposed for Sizewell C and small or advanced modular reactors (SMRs) which are rapidly coming onto the market. But more importantly we need to distinguish between an FOAK reactor that has never been licensed before and an NOAK (Nth Of A Kind) reactor for which design approval has already been awarded in either the US or Canada, or indeed another country that meets the UK’s exacting standards for nuclear licensing. With more than 20 SMR designs likely to make it to the licensing and construction stages in the next decade, the US, Canada and the UK can ill-afford to repeat the administrative and technical procedures given the time, staffing and financial constraints that each regulator is experiencing or is likely to experience once these designs are submitted. The US and Canadian regulators are already facing political pressure to speed up SMR design assessments and to be proportional given the size of these reactors when compared to giga scale reactors. The UK is limiting SMRs to a small number deemed most useful for the UK situation. However, adopting this line risks excluding exciting new technologies and applications from both the UK nuclear industry and the nation’s effort to decarbonise industry and power generation.

Of the possible new nuclear plants going through the mill in 2010, it was deemed necessary for their sile locations to be approved by 51 separate quangos. It was all a complete waste of time as in March 2011, Energy Secretary Huhne says Britain may back away from the use of nuclear energy because of safety fears and a potential rise in costs after the Fukushima disaster. No new nuclear plants were approved after  Sizewell B and Hinkley Point B in 1967. In other words, the process had become disapproval, not approval.

Future strategy: NOAK for Nuclear

The UK would be much better off if we abandoned trying to be first of a kind (FOAK) but aimed for Nth (NOAK). The advantages would be:

  • The GDA process could be immensely streamlined as the environmental issues could mostly be taken from predecessor countries and, if Canada and/or the US had already given approval, the safety aspects could be eliminated altogether. Instead of starting from scratch, new GDAs should only have to look at environmental issues that differ from GDAs already approved.  For example, if the radioactive elements of SMRs were sited underground, approval of one should automatically apply to another similarly sited. 

The average capital cost of SMR NOAK plants currently under development worldwide is approximately $5,130 per kilowatt electric (kWe), which is estimated to be 30% less than FOAK plants. However, it’s essential to note that specific costs can vary based on factors such as design, location, and technology.”

From these comparisons, we should conclude that both for large Giga Watt reactors and SMRs, the UK should abandon its enthusiasm for being the world leader. NOAK is quicker, cheaper and more reliable. Nuclear skills can be the better learned from other countries as well as developing our own. The car industry has proved not just to be a UK success story, but a NOAK success story too.  Nuclear should learn from that. 

Read More
Tim Worstall Tim Worstall

That targetted planning with strict conditionality

As we all know there’s a move to demand a new industrial policy. Government - those Rolls Royce minds - should determine what is done in our economy, by whom, how, and thereby gain such glorious results to the benefit of the nation.

Hmm, well, it’s an idea. Is there, though, some method by which we can test this? Before we gain that benefit to the nation or not? As it happens, yes. For the use of land has been nationalised since 1947. That’s when the Town and Country Planning Act did exactly that - centralised and nationalised who may use which piece of land for what to gain such glorious results to the benefit of the nation.

The Resolution Foundation has just told us how that has worked out over the 75 odd years:

If all households in the UK were fully exposed to our housing market, they would have to devote 22 per cent of their spending to housing services, far higher than the OECD average (17 per cent), and the highest level across the developed economies with the solitary exception of Finland.

We pay more than everyone else (except those Finns).

In 2018, for example, the floorspace per person in England was 38m2, compared to 43m2 in France (in 2020) and 46m2 in Germany (in 2017). We have been overtaken by Japan, at 40m2, and have less space per person than households in Taiwan, at 49m2. It is unsurprising that our homes are far smaller than in the US overall given its land mass but, strikingly, English floorspace per person is no bigger than that of residents of the central city district of the New York metropolitan area, who on average enjoy 43m2 of room.

We get less than everyone else, (even than those Finns).

Nationalisation of who may build houses where and in what form has led to more expensive housing of worse quality than places which do not have Rolls Royce minds doing that targetted planning with strict conditionality.

There we are, we’ve had a test of the contention and it’s a monstrously bad one. This is not, of course, a good thing to have happened. But it does have that silver lining of telling us what to do next.

First, and clearly, blow up the Town and Country Planning Act 1947 and successors. Blow it up properly, kablooie. Secondly, and even more obviously, tell those with arguing for targetted planning with strict conditionality where they can stick that idea.

Doing both of those will allow us to gain such glorious results to the benefit of the nation. Or, at least, do no worse than anyone else free of such impositions.

Read More
Tim Worstall Tim Worstall

A trade deficit doesn't create debt Mr. Timothy

If we are to have a national conversation about trade, manufacturing, debts, foreigners buying up the country and so on then it would be a good and reasonable idea to get the underlying right first:

Economic theory, and generations of politicians, told us not to worry about leaving manufacturing behind.

We’ve not left manufacturing behind. Manufacturing output is still within a few percent of all time highs. It’s double what it was when St Maggie came to power.

Since we moved to a floating exchange rate, economists and politicians have claimed this does not matter. But the trade deficit is both a product of our problems and a cause. It is a product because we do not make, do or sell enough to the rest of the world. It is a cause because the arising current account deficit leads us to sell assets to foreign investors and build up external debt, which leaves us with less control over our economy, and more exposed to investors’ interests and increases in international interest rates.

Economists are right here. Which, given that we are talking about economics seems appropriate.

Then there is the budget deficit and stock of debt…..In 2024-25 Britain plans to issue a record £271 billion in new gilts, and the strangers upon whom we depend will demand higher yields. They will wonder about inflation – higher in services than goods – and the value of Sterling, and price British debt accordingly.

And here’s it’s necessary to become detailed - in order to show why the economists are right.

There is no connection - none - between the size of the national debt and anything to do with trade. We have a national debt because generations of politicians micturate the wealth of the country up the wall. They continually spend more than we the people are willing to pay in taxes - or more than the politicians are willing to try extracting from us. That’s the cause, the only cause, of the national debt.

The trade defict is indeed balanced - exactly, precisely - by a surplus on the capital account. That’s definitional. But while capital might flow in from foreigners into debt instruments - like gilts - it doesn’t have to. It can purchase assets outright. This then leads to the old Warren Buffett argument about Squanderville. What happens when Johnny Foreigner owns all the capital assets in the country?

The UK trade deficit is - of the order of - £80 billion a year, meaning we need to have that same amount coming in on the capital account. In one recent year the UK produced £1 trillion in new wealth. That’s a 9% rise in total wealth - and we sold 8% of that new wealth to foreigners. Thus at the end of the year foreigners owned less of the national wealth than at the beginning of it.

This does not strike us as being a problem.

Painful things to political arguments, facts are. But we do think that facts are where the arguments should start so let’s try doing that, eh?

Our real contempt is reserved for this argument:

Classical economic theory holds that it does not matter who owns what, nor what is made where. Comparative advantage means countries do what they are good at, and buy what other countries provide. Thus, trade makes us all richer.

But this is not the case. First, governments get in the way.

So the solution to governments getting in the way is that we should have more government getting in the way in order to solve the problem of government getting in the way. We all should be contemptuous of that silliness.

Read More
Tim Worstall Tim Worstall

Oooh, what a fun argument this is, how very, very, fun

We seem to be watching a new elite consensus view being formed. As ever, it’s wrong, wholly wrong, but it is, we think, very fun indeed. In that forehead slapping, “No, really, they’re not trying this are they?“ definition of fun.

So, Ireland:

At the core of it were a number of key propositions. Ireland would have to embrace the idea of free trade, which meant encouraging competition and ending the protectionism that had been the hallmark of Irish economic policy under Lemass’s predecessor Éamon de Valera (whose economic philosophy had once been satirised as: “Burn everything English except their coal”). Most importantly, though, the strategy required that, henceforth, Ireland would have to be welcoming to foreign capital, which essentially meant being nice to multinationals – giving them generous tax breaks, assistance in finding locations for building and generally bending over backwards to attend to their needs.

Whitaker’s was a bold strategy, but it worked.

Ireland got rich by being standardly classical liberal sensible. OK.

There’s a massive shortage of affordable housing and an associated homelessness crisis: nearly 12,000 people in emergency accommodation and average monthly rents of €1,468;

But there’s a problem associated with those riches. Hmm. The source for this is:

The national budget surplus – essentially the difference between the amount of money coming in and going out in day-to-day expenditure – is forecast to add up to €65.2bn (£56.3bn) over the next four years.

Loadsamoney - Ireland is rich.

This has made Ireland an “outlier”, according to Prof Barrett, who pointed out more than 25% of tax revenue in the Republic of Ireland comes from corporation tax – compared an average figure of less than 10% across Europe.

The money’s made by stinging the capitalists. Rather a Laffer Curve there in fact - low rates means lots of capitalists and so beaucoup de revenue. Could be a plan for more countries really.

Nationwide, the touchstone social and political issue is housing.

Homelessness in Ireland is at a record high – with the most recent figures showing 12,600 people were in emergency accommodation in June.

But the housing shortage is having wider effects.

Ah, housing.

So, The Observer and the BBC agree here, and that is one of those elite consensi forming. Obviously. Ireland’s got rich because low taxes on corporations but this cannot be allowed - we can’t have an example of actual classical liberalism working now, can we - because housing.

And where the argument becomes, in the local argot, a bit of a cute hoor:

Rent controls are a fiscal policy that governments around the globe incorporate to control and regulate the amount that a landlord can charge for a lease of a property. The challenge lies in finding a balance between the rights of sitting tenants, new tenants and landlords. Rent regulation that is too strict can have a negative impact on the market, but complete deregulation can also have negative effects as it will push people into home ownership even where it is not feasible.

And:

Government measures to control rents have backfired and in many cases have led to an increase in rents, a new report has claimed.

The study by economist Jim Power suggests that rent pressure zones (RPZs), introduced in 2016 to limit rent price increases, have resulted in significant "rent rigidities" and an inefficient two-tier system where the proper maintenance of rental properties is no longer economically viable.

Rent controls are not a classical liberal policy. Rent controls are what are screwing the Irish rental property market.

Which is where that argument becomes so fun, isn’t it?

Classical liberalism makes a place rich. Not classical liberalism on rents makes housing expensive. But as the argument - that elite consensus view - is becoming it’s the bit that works, the stinging the capitalists for the costs of running the state that must go and it’s the idiocy of rent controls which is unquestioned and so presumably should stay.

Well, it would be a fun argument if it wasn’t palpably so damn stupid an argument.

Read More
Tim Worstall Tim Worstall

The Annals of State Efficiency - Only 75 years late

We note this from the National Audit Office:

In June 2023, NHS England (NHSE) published its Long Term Workforce Plan (LTWP). Based on an extensive modelling exercise, the LTWP estimated a starting shortfall between workforce supply and demand of approximately 150,000 full-time equivalent (FTE) NHS workers.

The important part of which is here:

For the first time @NHSEngland has produced modelling that combines planning its future services and planning its long-term workforce needs.

Now, government long term planning, we’re really pretty sure that’s going to be done badly. On the useful grounds that we know of absolutely no example at all when it has been done well.

But the British government has been in charge of the planning of the medical workforce since around the time of WWII. For it is government that decides how many doctors and nurses will be trained - they’ve long controlled the budgets for that education. This is, of course, why we’ve so many of both imported as domestic supply has fallen so woefully behind demand.

But put aside our prejudices about such planning. Put aside even the good or bad sense of it. Just relish the efficiency of this particular example.

The government, in that form of the NHS, is only 75 years late in having a plan for that thing that they’ve been in charge of all these decades.

And there are people who disagree with us when we mutter that perhaps government planning isn’t the way to do things, eh?

Read More
Tim Worstall Tim Worstall

Absolute poverty numbers prove a couple of things

Much whingeing about the absolute poverty numbers. The Joseph Rowntree folk seem to be taking over the The Guardian about it - situation normal in fact.

Absolute poverty, in this sense, is who is below the relative poverty level of 2010/11. The relative poverty level, as we know, is less than 60% of median household income adjusted for household size (and etc, etc). Absolute poverty, in this sense, is using the 2010/11 measure of relative poverty and comparing to that. There’s a trick used here. We’re old enough to recall when it was relative poverty in 2000/01 that was used. Given that poverty by that measure seemed to be disappearing real fast the rebasing was done. After all, calls for ever more stringent taxation to beat poverty cannot be maintained if poverty is disappearing before our very eyes now, can they? As Chris Snowdon points out, properly measured absolute poverty has fallen from 85% of the population in 1961 to the 14 to 18% of today.

From which we can gain one useful lesson. Economic growth is important - it kills poverty. This means that we can reject all that degrowth nonsense because as we keep being told beating poverty is our prime economic directive.

Cool.

But there’s also one more thing here. This rise in absolute poverty is more an artefact than a reality. Because this:

Inflation-linked benefits and tax credits will rise by 6.7% from April 2024, in line with the Consumer Prices Index (CPI) rate of inflation in September 2023. For example, in 2024/25 Universal Credit standard allowances will increase: From £292.11 to £311.68 per month for single people aged under 25.

Significant portions of - if not all - income of those in absolute poverty will be coming from the benefits system. Benefits are uprated for inflation after the inflation has happened. The measures of absolute poverty are before those benefits upratings. The problem will be - largely - solved when the benefits are uprated. We’re just in that interregnum before they are.

But we can also take another lesson from this. Which is that Modern Monetary Theory does not work. The inflation was indeed caused by that vast money print and spending into the real economy. Which is MMT of course. But if MMT increases poverty in this manner - which it does, the inflation is compensated for later - then we cannot achieve our prime directive of reducing poverty if we use MMT.

So, two useful lessons from these absolute poverty numbers. Both degrowth and MMT are bad ideas not to be used. Well, sure, we know that anyway but nice to have another string to the bow - they increase poverty, see?

Read More
Tim Worstall Tim Worstall

That Labour Theory of Value....

To cast the Labour Theory of Value into colloquial terms - including the conclusion often reached from it.

It’s only human labour that really adds value to things. Therefore, all the value added to something should flow to labour. If capital, or the capitalists - who have not laboured to add value - gain some of that value than that’s expropriation. We should therefore stop that and make sure that labour gains all the value added.

Yes, pretty crude but at the general level of understanding that is what is meant by it.

A veteran metal detectorist hit the jackpot when he turned up late to a group dig only to stumble across the largest gold nugget ever found in England after just 20 minutes of searching.

Richard Brock, 67, travelled three-and-a-half hours from his home in Somerset in May 2023 to join an organised expedition on farmland in the Shropshire Hills.

Despite his metal detector not in full working order, Mr Brock, who has been metal detecting for 35 years, discovered the biggest find of his life after unearthing a 64.8-gram (about 2.28 ounces) golden nugget.

To a useful level of accuracy that’s some £4,000 worth of gold.

The nugget is estimated to sell for £30,000.

Well, maybe it will and maybe it won’t. But this does pose a terrible problem for that Labour Theory of Value.

Yes, of course, we can go through any number of rathole iterations and insist that the labour of detectoring is what added the £26k in value and all that. Or say that natural finds are different or summat.

But what we’ve actually got there is that the prices humans allocate to things are not objective. They are subjective. £4k of gold becomes £30k of nugget because there’s a nice story attached.

We can also continue down the rathole iterations and insist that the absence of a metal detector would lead to no value at all, therefore capital is being expropriated by not gaining all, let alone any, of that value.

But the correct answer here is that the Labour Theory is simply wrong. Sure, we can construct ethical or moral systems in which it should be true. We can even insist that humans be reformed so as to make it true - tho’ we’d observe that New Soviet Man sure took a long time comin’.

Reality is simply that humans do not price things by the labour value in their production. Prices are subjective opinions, not objective realities. Sure, when 8 billion subjectives are aggregated we get to the “real price” of something but we’ve not an objective analysis underlying all of that. Given this it’s not possible to have an objective split of the value added - for that value just isn’t commensurable in that manner.

That is, the Labour Theory of Value is just great except for the one thing - it doesn’t apply to us, us humans, and the prices and values we apply to things.

Read More
Tim Worstall Tim Worstall

One of those times we agree with George Monbiot

As ever, it’s only the diagnosis, not the solution:

The primaries won’t deliver a perfect system. We’ll still be stuck with a centralised and coercive politics, unmatched to the needs of the complex system we call society, based on the illegitimate concepts of presumed consent and remote decision-making. We will properly reclaim that power only when our representative politics are accompanied by participatory and deliberative decision-making.

George is talking about how the people who might get voted in as MPs are chosen. We are - as is our wont - rather more radical. Make who is the MP irrelevant to those areas of life.

We agree entirely that there are vast areas of life that simply shouldn’t be subject to presumed consent and remote decision-making. We agree that those vast areas of life should be dealt with in a participatory and deliberative fashion. Further, locally, by the people directly involved, without imposition by the centre or even the tyranny of the majority.

That means simply not having government, nor the majoritarian tyranny of democracy, involved at all. Just remove government from those areas of life - leave ‘em be for individuals and groups of people as they wish to combine and accumulate to get on with it. Remove, entirely, the power of other people to determine and make it direct decision making by those concerned.

You know, free markets.

Sure, there are some things where that majoritarian imposition is necessary. But the key word there is “some” and the correct definition of that some is “very many fewer than it is currently applied to”.

In a radically free country how we choose the people who might run for the job of getting the bins collected becomes some mild trivia, of interest to the occasional anorak and no more. So, the way to achieve that better politics is to be radically free, no?

Read More
Tim Worstall Tim Worstall

So cheap, renewables, so, so, cheap

We’re fully aware of the claims about how much - how little - it costs to generate electricity using renewables. We’d also point to this:

A £58bn plan to rewire Great Britain’s electricity grid to connect up new windfarms off the coast of Scotland is expected to trigger tensions with communities along the route.

The £58 billion is a cost of renewables. It’s entirely possible that it’s a worthwhile cost - equally, that it isn’t. But it’s definitely a cost of renewables.

The ESO said three times as much undersea cabling would be laid than onshore infrastructure by 2035 and estimated its blueprint would add £15bn to the economy, creating 20,000 jobs a year.

Those 20,000 jobs are also a cost of renewables, not a benefit.

Note that all of this is true whatever one’s view of climate change, the necessity or not of dealing with it and so on. These are costs of doing that dealing. So, cheap may not be quite the right word. For the cost of renewables is not to be measured by the generation of a watt, it’s the cost of delivering, reliably, a watt to when and where it is to be used.

But our real ire is aimed at this:

Britain’s electricity networks will not hit net zero until 2035, National Grid has said, undermining a key pledge by Labour to hit that target by 2030.

The deadline prompted a backlash from Ed Miliband, the shadow energy secretary, who said a Labour government would make ESO accelerate its programme to hit the 2030 target. A spokesman said: “We said 2030 for decarbonising the grid and we meant it.”

No, not who is demanding what, which political party etc. Rather, that something like this is being determined by political pledges in an electoral (well, almost certainly one) year.

Whether we have a decarbonised grid or not depends upon the benefits of having one against the costs of having one. Accelerating the process makes it more expensive - and thus reduces the net benefit of doing so. It is possible to calculate either way. But who believes that anyone is? We’re being treated to political performativity over the spending of £58 billion and perhaps more. That is, we’re not being treated to rational decision making in the slightest.

Which is why we don’t like politics as the method of economic decision making. Simply because the economic decisions are not, therefore and thereby, made upon economic grounds.

This is not a party political point in terms of who it is demanding whichever - it’s a complaint about party politics itself as a method of economic decision making.

Read More
Your subscription could not be saved. Please try again.
Your subscription has been successful.

Blogs by email